The coronavirus pandemic and the depression that follows will leave the U.S. with a lot of unpayable debts. Consumers who lose their jobs will have difficulty making payments on credit cards, auto loans and student loans. Businesses that lose sales will default on loans and bonds.

In a bygone era when the economy was less dependent on a web of debt obligations, this might not have mattered as much. But the U.S. economy has loaded up on debt over the years:

This doesn’t mean that the U.S. is living beyond its means; the vast majority of this borrowing is money that Americans owe to each other. But it does indicate that the modern economy is built on a sort of just-in-time financial supply chain, in which the solvency of businesses and households depends on the prompt arrival of a vast number of debt-service payments from other businesses and households. Disrupt that delicate web and much economic activity can grind to a halt. This is probably why asset bubbles hurt the economy a lot more when they’re accompanied by high levels of debt. Coronavirus, of course, will be worse than any asset bubble.

The damage to the web of debt will hamper the U.S. economy’s recovery. Businesses that survive with diminished revenue will struggle for years to pay down debt before they’re able to start investing and expanding again. Debt will likewise hold companies back from changing their business models to better fit the demands of the post-pandemic economy. Workers burdened by debt will have a harder time switching jobs or going back to school, making the labor market less efficient at allocating talent to where it needs to go.

Bailouts are one potential solution. By turning business and household debt into government debt, the Treasury can effectively consolidate the complex web of debt into a simpler relationship. But bailouts will inevitably be politicized, as they were in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis; everyone will argue that they deserve bailouts more than others, and many will be resentful at the eventual allocation of government largesse. Fighting over the spoils could in turn make bailouts much smaller than they ought to be; this happened in 2009, when Tea Party anger steered the government away from bailing out most homeowners.

But there’s another way that the government can shrink the mountain of debt weighing down the U.S. economy: inflation. Because most interest payments are fixed in nominal terms, inflation makes existing debt less important in real terms. Raising the long-term inflation target from the current 2% to a still-modest 4% would substantially increase the rate at which debt effectively vanishes.

The U.S. has used inflation this way before. Economists Joshua Aizenman and Nancy Marion wrote:

The average inflation rate over this period [from 1946 to 1955] was 4.2%...inflation reduced the 1946 [federal] debt/GDP ratio by almost 40% within a decade.

A decade of 4% inflation today would do the same for total debt, not just government debt.

First « 1 2 » Next